The theory behind the principle-agent problem was developed by Harvard Business School Professor Michael Jensen and economist and management professor William H. Meckling. The principle-agent problem describes a conflict in priorities between a person or group and the representative authorized to make decisions on their behalf.
Understanding the principle-agent problem
In a 1976 paper titled Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, Jensen and Meckling proposed an ownership structure theory to avoid what they defined as the separation of ownership and control.
This separation occurs when the interests of the agent and the principle diverge. When one person (the agent) is allowed to make decisions on behalf of another person (the principle), a conflict of interest can sometimes result. The agent may have more information than the principle, which means the principle cannot predict how the agent will act. As such, the agent tends to pursue their own goals instead of prioritizing the goals of the principle.
This scenario is often problematic for the principle, who typically retains ownership of assets and are liable for losses incurred despite delegating some degree of control and authority to the agent.
Agency costs in the principle-agent problem
Agency costs are incurred when the interests of the agent and the principle diverge and need to be resolved.
For example, a traveling sales executive may prefer to stay in expensive hotels or eat at fancy restaurants. In so doing, the individual is looking after their own interests while adding little value to the company or its shareholders.
The agency cost of this behavior then decreases the financial performance of the company. In addition to paying high expense bills, the company may also incur costs from hiring an external auditor to analyze its financial statements. It may also be forced to terminate the employee in question and engage in an expensive and exhaustive recruitment process.
To that end, there are two categories of agency costs:
- Costs incurred by the principle (shareholder) to prevent the agent (management team) from prioritizing their needs over shareholder interests.
- Costs incurred by the principle (company) when the agent (management team) uses company resources for their own benefit.
How can the principle-agent problem be addressed?
The solution to the principle-agent problem revolves around aligning the interests of both parties.
Here is how this might be achieved:
- Contract design – or the creation of a contract framework between the principle and the agent. This ensures potential sources of information asymmetry are clearly defined, meaning the agent is less likely to act in a way that furthers their own interests. Furthermore, the contract should stipulate how the actions of the agent will be monitored to increase compliance.
- Performance evaluation and compensation – while monitoring is important, performance compensation provides extra motivation for the agent to act in a way that aligns with the principle’s interests. Performance should be evaluated subjectively because this is a more flexible and balanced method for complex tasks or arrangements. Depending on the situation, the principle may offer the agent deferred compensation, stock options, or profit-sharing.
Key takeaways:
- The principle-agent problem describes a conflict in priorities between a person or group and the representative authorized to make decisions on their behalf. It was first introduced by Michael Jensen and William H. Meckling in 1976.
- The principle-agent problem states that when the interests of the agent and principle diverge, agency costs are incurred. These costs result when the principle tries to prevent the agent from prioritizing their needs over the needs of shareholders. Costs are also incurred when an agent misuses company funds for their own benefit without adding value to the bottom line.
- The principle-agent problem can be rectified by smart contract design. Contracts should identify potential sources of information asymmetry and include a plan for monitoring the actions of the agent. What’s more, the agent should be financially motivated to act in a way that benefits the principle.
Key Highlights
- Introduction to the Principle-Agent Problem:
- The Principle-Agent Problem was developed by Michael Jensen and William H. Meckling.
- It addresses a conflict between a representative (agent) making decisions on behalf of another person or group (principal).
- Understanding the Problem:
- The problem arises when the interests of the agent and the principal diverge.
- The agent, who makes decisions, may prioritize personal goals over those of the principal.
- Information asymmetry, where the agent possesses more information than the principal, can lead to this conflict.
- Agency Costs:
- Agency costs emerge when the agent’s behavior deviates from the principal’s interests.
- Examples include agents incurring excessive expenses without contributing value or misusing company resources.
- These costs negatively impact the company’s financial performance and may lead to additional expenses, such as hiring auditors or recruitment.
- Addressing the Problem:
- Alignment of interests is key to solving the principle-agent problem.
- Smart contract design is crucial, defining roles and monitoring mechanisms to mitigate information asymmetry.
- Performance evaluation and compensation motivate agents to act in the principal’s interests.
- Subjective performance evaluation provides flexibility for complex tasks, and compensation may involve deferred payments, stock options, or profit-sharing.
- Key Takeaways:
- The Principle-Agent Problem involves conflicts between agents making decisions and principals on whose behalf they act.
- Divergent interests between the two parties lead to agency costs.
- Solutions involve well-designed contracts, monitoring mechanisms, and performance-based compensation to align agent and principal interests.
Connected Economic Concepts
Positive and Normative Economics
Related Strategy Concepts: Go-To-Market Strategy, Marketing Strategy, Business Models, Tech Business Models, Jobs-To-Be Done, Design Thinking, Lean Startup Canvas, Value Chain, Value Proposition Canvas, Balanced Scorecard, Business Model Canvas, SWOT Analysis, Growth Hacking, Bundling, Unbundling, Bootstrapping, Venture Capital, Porter’s Five Forces, Porter’s Generic Strategies, Porter’s Five Forces, PESTEL Analysis, SWOT, Porter’s Diamond Model, Ansoff, Technology Adoption Curve, TOWS, SOAR, Balanced Scorecard, OKR, Agile Methodology, Value Proposition, VTDF Framework, BCG Matrix, GE McKinsey Matrix, Kotter’s 8-Step Change Model.
Main Free Guides: